New Marketplace

Financial Incentives and Vulnerable Populations — Will Alternative Payment Models Help or Hurt?

Article · May 21, 2018


Interview with Dr. Karen Joynt Maddox on alternative payment models and disincentives for treating high-risk patients.

 

There is broad agreement that fee-for-service reimbursement does too little to encourage the provision of efficient, high-value care. Consequently, Medicare and other payers are increasingly moving toward alternative payment models (APMs), which disrupt the fee-for-service system by incorporating quality and cost targets into reimbursement. Examples include accountable care organizations (ACOs), which hold providers responsible for meeting annual cost and quality targets, and bundled payment programs, which hold them responsible for meeting cost and quality targets during 30-, 60-, or 90-day care episodes.

In the best-case scenario, clinicians will respond to APMs’ incentives by improving care coordination and integration, which may particularly benefit vulnerable populations with higher-than-average medical and social needs. On the other hand, there may be incentives for clinicians to avoid caring for these groups, who are at risk for high costs or poor outcomes in part because of factors beyond clinicians’ control. Understanding APMs’ potential consequences for vulnerable populations is critical if we wish to maximize benefits and reduce harms.

Vulnerable populations, such as people living in poverty and people with disabilities, disproportionately incur high health care costs and have poor health outcomes. Under fee-for-service reimbursement, there has been little financial incentive to focus on attracting or improving care for these groups, who often need low-margin services such as primary and behavioral health care. Under APMs, by contrast, the highest-cost beneficiaries present the greatest opportunities for achieving savings, particularly in terms of modifiable costs such as emergency department visits for poorly controlled diabetes or hypertension, or unmet mental health needs. Consequently, APMs may encourage clinicians to coordinate care and pursue clinical innovations such as behavioral health integration for these groups. Such innovation could improve care and reduce disparities affecting historically underserved groups.

Empirical data, however, have been mixed. For example, in the Massachusetts Blue Cross Blue Shield Alternative Quality Contract, which replaced fee-for-service reimbursement with global payments tied to quality measures, quality improved the most for enrollees in areas with lower socioeconomic status, and disparities between these populations and more affluent ones narrowed.1 Similarly, in the Physician Group Practice Demonstration, the precursor to the Medicare Shared Savings Program, people who were enrolled in both Medicare and Medicaid had the greatest reductions in costs and unplanned rehospitalizations.2 In the Medicare Shared Savings Program itself, the ACOs most likely to achieve shared savings were those with the highest proportion of dually enrolled or disabled people,3 but a recent study showed that reductions in hospitalizations accrued roughly evenly in high-risk and low-risk groups.4

Yet APMs have the potential to be harmful. Current risk-adjustment methods are not sophisticated enough to reliably distinguish poor-quality care from high medical and social risk. Risk-adjustment models for readmission, for example, are notoriously poor, in part because they generally do not account for social factors, such as poverty, that are known to influence readmission. Cost measures have similar limitations: research has shown that care for people dually enrolled in Medicare and Medicaid costs more than care for people who are not, even after coexisting conditions are accounted for, probably because of such factors as functional status and social support that are not included in current risk-adjustment models.3 As a result, hospitals or clinics with a high proportion of poor patients may lose money under APMs through no fault of their own. Particularly in programs with a high level of downside financial risk, there is a powerful incentive for clinicians to avoid providing care for high-risk patients, which could have meaningful consequences for access to care.

Effect of Value-Based Payment Programs on Providers That Serve the Poor

For the three hospital programs, the Disproportionate Share Hospital (DSH) index, a measure of the proportion of care provided to low-income patients, was used to define the top quintile. For the Physician and End-Stage Renal Disease programs, the proportion of beneficiaries dually enrolled in Medicare and Medicaid was used to define the top quintile. Data are from U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. Click To Enlarge.

Indeed, a number of studies have demonstrated that value-based payment programs disproportionately penalize providers that serve poor people (see graph); such penalties could cause providers to avoid caring for these groups. As value-based payment and APMs begin to be used for physician reimbursement, these problems could be exacerbated, since there is greater economic segregation5 — and probably lower ability to bear risk — at the practice level than at the hospital or health system level.

APMs could also harm vulnerable populations if cost targets provide incentives for providers to cut back too far on services. This effect was a concern under 1990s capitation programs, which were seen as encouraging clinicians to withhold services from patients. Although the use of quality measures may protect against this reaction to some degree, such measures are neither comprehensive nor specific enough to do so in all instances. For example, poor and minority patients are less likely than others to undergo percutaneous coronary intervention after myocardial infarction5; if clinicians face the added pressure of financial incentives to reduce spending, access could be reduced even further for these groups. Such harms are insidious and, without a prospective effort to monitor and track such consequences, could easily be ignored.

I believe that APMs should reward clinicians for improving the things they can improve, while not penalizing them or holding them accountable for the things they can’t. Policymakers who wish to accelerate the growth of APMs while avoiding unnecessary harm to vulnerable populations and the clinicians who care for them might consider crafting payment models that adhere to a few key principles.

First, given the evidence that poverty and functional status, among other factors, strongly influence patient outcomes, APMs could include these factors in risk adjustment. Failing to account for them means underestimating the quality of care provided by clinicians serving high-risk populations and overestimating the quality provided by those serving low-risk populations; in many programs, the result is a transfer of money from clinicians caring for high-risk patients to ones caring for low-risk patients. Such redistribution is unfair to clinicians and patients and is not an appropriate path.

Second, in cases in which risk adjustment is inadequate to permit fair comparisons among providers, APMs could evaluate participants on improvement rather than solely on achievement. If one physician practice serves an affluent, low-risk population and another serves an impoverished, high-risk population, it may be infeasible to fairly compare the two groups’ admission rates for diabetes, given the limited information available in administrative claims data. Both practices, however, could be rewarded for improving, and be adequately resourced and supported to do so. Such an approach could drive advances in quality without penalizing practices serving more complex populations and could be implemented within rulemaking rather than requiring legislation in many current APMs.

Third, APMs could reward quality improvements proportionally rather than taking an all-or-nothing approach. Currently, a primary care doctor who helps a patient with uncomplicated hypertension to reduce her systolic blood pressure from 145 to 140 mm Hg would achieve the quality metric of “blood pressure under control,” but a doctor who helps a patient with chronic kidney disease and diabetes reduce his blood pressure from 190 to 145 mm Hg — an accomplishment with much more profound clinical consequences — would receive no credit. Under a proportional-improvement–based method, clinicians would have incentives to focus on patients whose conditions had the most room for improvement. Such a system would require a more sophisticated approach to quality measurement, but as we increasingly attend to population health and capture more data electronically, it is an essential and increasingly feasible proposition.

Fourth, if we truly want APMs to drive a focus on the most vulnerable among us, we should explicitly design them to do so. We could link payment to measures that examine access to care among dually enrolled beneficiaries, or outcomes specifically among high-risk populations, or reductions in disparities. Doing so would harness financial incentives to drive improvement in the populations that need it most.

The further we move toward APMs with financial incentives that encourage providers to innovate, address social needs affecting health, and fundamentally change the way we provide care, the better things will be for our most vulnerable patients. While some organizations may be driven by a moral imperative to address social determinants of health, financial incentives could persuade organizations that might not otherwise do so to focus on their neediest clients. However, if we introduce such incentives without close attention to how APMs affect providers who serve vulnerable populations, we risk causing more harm than good. As APMs proliferate, we will have to consider these issues critically and track programs’ effects closely.


SOURCE INFORMATION

From the Department of Medicine, Cardiovascular Division, Washington University School of Medicine, St. Louis.

1. Song Z, Rose S, Chernew ME, Safran DG. Lower- versus higher-income populations in the Alternative Quality Contract: improved quality and similar spending. Health Aff (Millwood) 2017;36:74-82. CrossRef | Medline
2. Colla CH, Wennberg DE, Meara E, et al. Spending differences associated with the Medicare Physician Group Practice Demonstration. JAMA 2012;308:1015-1023. CrossRef | Medline
3. Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. Report to Congress: social risk factors and performance under Medicare’s value-based purchasing programs. Washington, DC: Department of Health and Human Services, December 2016.
4. McWilliams JM, Chernew ME, Landon BE. Medicare ACO program savings not tied to preventable hospitalizations or concentrated among high-risk patients. Health Aff (Millwood) 2017;36:2085-2093. CrossRef | Medline
5. Hannan EL, Zhong Y, Walford G, et al. Underutilization of percutaneous coronary intervention for ST-elevation myocardial infarction in Medicaid patients relative to private insurance patients. J Interv Cardiol 2013;26:470-481. Medline

This Perspective article originally appeared in The New England Journal of Medicine.

New call for submissions ­to NEJM Catalyst

Now inviting longform articles

Connect

A weekly email newsletter featuring the latest actionable ideas and practical innovations from NEJM Catalyst.

Learn More »

More From New Marketplace
Washington State Health Care Authority Center of Excellence joint replacement elements and outcomes of program produces strong patient experience scores

Improving Care by Redesigning Payment

A state-run center of excellence uses benefit design to improve outcomes while controlling cost.

Alaigh03_pullquote aco and bundled payment co-exist

ACOs and Bundled Payments: How the Two Can and Should Coexist

The integration of primary care and specialty care physicians through adoption of both payment models will lead to synergistic value.

Pham03_pullquote payment and delivery-system reform

Payment and Delivery-System Reform — The Next Phase

To truly redesign a system, one has to take a holistic approach and move multiple levers in concert, rather than fiddling with individual factors serially and hoping for a coordinated effect.

A Connected Health Data and Service Ecoystem - digital health platform convener

Convening a Digitally Enabled Ecosystem to Address the Chronic Disease Burden of an Underserved Community

Disrupted by technologies, health care needs ecosystem-based solutions for integration and equitable access.

Shachar01_pullquote value-based care fee-for-service fraud and abuse laws

Are Fraud and Abuse Laws Stifling Value-Based Care?

To realize the true potential of value-based care, we must update the underlying assumptions in our fraud and abuse regulatory system.

Porter02_SBUs and IPUs pullquote1

What 21st Century Health Care Should Learn from 20th Century Business

Just as there is no such thing as good marketing or good manufacturing, there is no such thing as good primary care — it completely depends on how that care is tailored to meet the needs of patients with a particular medical condition.

Missouri Show Me Health Plans Cost Calculator for Health Insurance Enrollment screen shot - health insurance education

Facilitating Health Insurance Enrollment in an Uncertain Environment

Lessons learned from five years of open enrollment in Missouri.

Birkmeyer02_pullquote - national physician practices NPPs

Aggregators, Innovators, and the Resurgence of National Physician Practices

A perspective on the growth of NPPs and the ideological divide between for-profit and nonprofit providers.

Hospital-based ACOs Key Capabilities Are Different Based on Level of Risk

Hospital-based ACOs Face Challenges in Tracking Performance Indicators

A focus on bundled payments for specific episodes of care — versus the broad changes required in an ACO model — may be a more effective method for ACO participants to develop capabilities required to measure utilization, cost, and revenue metrics.

Medicaid Referral to Specialist by the Numbers without eConsults

Can eConsults Save Medicaid?

How eConsults unlock medical expertise for the underserved.

Connect

A weekly email newsletter featuring the latest actionable ideas and practical innovations from NEJM Catalyst.

Learn More »

Topics

Payment and Delivery-System Reform — The…

To truly redesign a system, one has to take a holistic approach and move multiple…

Bundled Payments

53 Articles

Improving Care by Redesigning Payment

A state-run center of excellence uses benefit design to improve outcomes while controlling cost.

Improving Care by Redesigning Payment

A state-run center of excellence uses benefit design to improve outcomes while controlling cost.

Insights Council

Have a voice. Join other health care leaders effecting change, shaping tomorrow.

Apply Now