New Marketplace

Addressing Generic-Drug Market Failures — The Case for Establishing a Nonprofit Manufacturer

Article · June 18, 2018

Interview with Dan Liljenquist on generic-drug market failures and the creation of a nonprofit drug manufacturer.

 

Robust competition usually keeps the price of generic drugs well below that of brand-name drugs. When there is little or no competition, however, generic-drug manufacturers can substantially increase prices, and drug shortages may occur. Such market failures can compromise care and negatively affect patients, health care providers, government insurance programs, and private health plans.1,2

One strategy for generic-drug manufacturers seeking to maximize profit is to enter a market where they have the capacity to produce enough of a drug to meet market demand and the power to dictate the drug’s price. In 2010, for example, Valeant acquired the rights to Syprine (trientine hydrochloride), a drug invented in the 1960s to treat Wilson’s disease, a rare condition, and subsequently raised its price by more than 3000% for a monthly supply, from $652 to $21,267. Similarly, in 2015 Turing acquired the rights to Daraprim (pyrimethamine), a drug used to treat toxoplasmosis, which has a market of only 6000 patients in the United States, so that one manufacturer could supply the entire market. Turing then raised the price of Daraprim by more than 5000% for one tablet, from $13.50 to $750. In these and other cases, policymakers and economists have asked, “Why don’t other manufacturers enter this seemingly lucrative market?”

One reason is that the start-up costs for entering generic-drug markets can be substantial relative to the size of the market for a particular drug because of the initial investment required and the cost of obtaining Food and Drug Administration (FDA) approval. More important, however, is the threat that the current manufacturer (Valeant, in the case of Syprine, or Turing, in the case of Daraprim) will drastically reduce the price of its product once the FDA grants approval for the new entrant. The threat of a price collapse imposes a substantial financial risk for prospective for-profit entrants. Although the FDA and Congress have taken steps to foster greater competition in generic-drug markets,3 such as offering expedited review and restricting the use of limited-distribution networks (in which a manufacturer allows only a certain number of pharmacies to distribute a specialty drug), many generic drugs are still supplied by a small number of manufacturers. Using limited-distribution networks can obstruct access to drug samples that competing manufacturers are seeking in order to conduct testing to submit a generic or biosimilar drug application to the FDA.4

We believe that market-based solutions are an important alternative approach to stimulating competition in generic-drug markets. One such solution is to establish a nonprofit generic-drug manufacturer with the explicit mission of producing affordable versions of essential drugs and ensuring a stable supply of such products. A consortium of hospitals and health plans, including Intermountain Healthcare, Trinity Health, SSM Health, and Ascension, in collaboration with the Department of Veterans Affairs and philanthropists, is following this approach and developing a nonprofit generic-drug manufacturer code-named Project Rx.

A nonprofit generic-drug manufacturer, which cannot sell equity shares, can initially be funded by philanthropic contributions. It can contract with existing manufacturing facilities or, if necessary, establish its own facilities and rely on guaranteed purchases by institutional partners, such as hospitals, health plans, and government agencies. These institutions, which need uninterrupted access to generic drugs and have a financial incentive to purchase them at reasonable prices, will provide a stable revenue source for the manufacturer.

Hospitals and other institutional partners know which drugs they need (and in what quantities), the price and shortage histories for various drugs, and the competitiveness of each market and its vulnerability to market failures. Before a nonprofit manufacturer begins finding investors and initiating production, it can enter into agreements to sell generic drugs directly to these institutional partners at predetermined low prices and with a contracted minimum volume. Such purchasing agreements protect the manufacturer from being forced out of the market by a for-profit manufacturer that reduces the price of a competing product. Donations from philanthropists and institutional partners can be used to finance a nonprofit manufacturer’s start-up costs (usually about $200,000 per drug, which covers the FDA Abbreviated New Drug Application filing fee and bioequivalence testing).5 With its distinctive nonprofit orientation, capital structure, and marketing strategy, such a manufacturer might overcome entry barriers that deter potential for-profit entrants from competing in some generic-drug markets, since it cannot be forced out because of price changes in the market. If an existing for-profit manufacturer reduces the price of its product to compete with the nonprofit manufacturer, patients and payers will benefit from greater access to cheaper drugs.

Once a nonprofit manufacturer enters the market, it will have the potential to provide a stable supply of generic drugs at an affordable price. Its cost of capital will be low because it doesn’t need to pursue a certain level of profit to attract equity investors. The legal constraint that it cannot distribute earnings and the relationship it maintains with its institutional purchasers ensure that the manufacturer will pursue a cost-plus strategy — generating only enough revenue to cover costs and maintain a limited surplus for financial viability — rather than a profit-maximization strategy. Furthermore, the manufacturer’s tax-exempt status will allow it to rely on charitable contributions as well as patent donations from brand-name drug manufacturers to bring generic drugs to the market, thereby lowering its cost of operation.

A nonprofit manufacturer can make some generic drugs substantially more affordable. For example, the cost of manufacturing one Daraprim tablet through outsourcing contracts is less than 10 cents. Assuming that a $200,000 one-time cost of entering the market for Daraprim is to be paid off within 1 year, the cost for each tablet would be approximately 35 cents (10 cents of manufacturing cost plus 25 cents of average one-time cost). Even allowing for a 10-fold markup to cover administrative and other expenses, the nonprofit manufacturer can set a price of $3.50 per tablet — less than 0.5% of the price of Daraprim after it was acquired by Turing ($750) and roughly one quarter of the price before the acquisition ($13.75).

To ensure that a nonprofit manufacturer’s operations are aligned with its core mission, its institutional partners and major donors can serve on its board of trustees. Participation on the board by institutional partners, who have a financial interest in keeping prices low, will strengthen the board’s fiduciary responsibility and further constrain the manufacturer from engaging in price-gouging behaviors. The manufacturer’s portfolio of products might initially be limited to drugs with the most severe price distortion and supply shortages as well as drugs that are in high demand among its institutional partners. One place to start could be generic injectable drugs, which are used primarily for hospital inpatients, account for most of the drugs on the FDA’s list of current drug shortages, and have experienced substantial price increases in recent years. As the capacity of the nonprofit manufacturer expands, its product portfolio can be diversified to include a broader range of generic drugs, and its distribution channels can be expanded to include group purchasing organizations and pharmacy benefit managers. Eventually, the presence of nonprofit manufacturers will bring increased competition to areas of the generic-drug market where market failure is prevalent, which will motivate for-profit manufacturers to reduce prices and stabilize supply.

The complex nature of market failures for generic drugs implies that a single alternative business model cannot address all aspects of this problem. We believe that Project Rx may drive other nonprofit and for-profit manufacturers to enter generic-drug markets, compete among themselves, and collectively improve market efficiency and broaden access to generic drugs.


SOURCE INFORMATION

From Intermountain Healthcare, Salt Lake City (D.L.); the Johns Hopkins Carey Business School, Washington, DC (G.B.); and the Johns Hopkins Bloomberg School of Public Health, Baltimore (G.F.A.).

1. Alpern JD, Stauffer WM, Kesselheim AS. High-cost generic drugs — implications for patients and policymakers. N Engl J Med 2014;371:1859-1862. Free Full Text | Web of Science | Medline
2. Fox ER, Sweet BV, Jensen V. Drug shortages: a complex health care crisis. Mayo Clin Proc 2014;89:361-373. CrossRef | Medline
3. Greene JA, Anderson G, Sharfstein JM. Role of the FDA in affordability of off-patent pharmaceuticals. JAMA 2016;315:461-462. CrossRef | Web of Science | Medline
4. Karas L, Shermock KM, Proctor C, Socal M, Anderson GF. Limited distribution networks stifle competition in the generic and biosimilar drug industries. Am J Manag Care 2018;24(4):e122-e127. Medline
5. Generic drug user fee amendments. Silver Spring, MD: Food and Drug Administration, 2018 (https://www.fda.gov/ForIndustry/UserFees/GenericDrugUserFees/default.htm).

This Perspective article originally appeared in The New England Journal of Medicine.

New call for submissions ­to NEJM Catalyst

Now inviting longform articles

Connect

A weekly email newsletter featuring the latest actionable ideas and practical innovations from NEJM Catalyst.

Learn More »

More From New Marketplace
Strongwater08_pullquote primary care value proposition and disruptive innovation

The Evolution of Primary Care: Embracing Innovation While Protecting the Core Value

Primary care must leverage disruptive innovations to ensure that patients receive first-access, comprehensive, coordinated, continuous care that is woven into a seamlessly integrated system.

Berns01_pullquote nephrologists dialysis facility joint venture conflicts of interest

Dialysis-Facility Joint-Venture Ownership — Hidden Conflicts of Interest

Despite potential benefits, joint ventures between nephrologists and dialysis companies raise legal and ethical concerns because of participants’ conflicts of interest and lack of transparency.

Fee-for-Service Continues to Account for the Majority of Revenue

New Marketplace Survey: Transitioning Payment Models: Fee-for-Service to Value-Based Care

In a survey of the NEJM Catalyst Insights Council sponsored by Optum, respondents express enthusiasm for value-based care but have conflicting opinions about just how far along that path they should go.

Sample Report Comparing Individual Patient-Reported Outcome Measures with FORCE-TJR National Norms

The Essential Role of Patient-Centered Registries in an Era of Electronic Health Records

Smartly designed patient-centered registries capture longitudinal data to augment EHRs and enhance quality improvement, policy, and research efforts.

Murray02_pullquote surgical care bundled payments accountable care organizations

Surgical Value — Beyond Bundled Payments

The surgeon has a crucial role in defining value for patients in a population — and not just when that patient is in need of the surgeon’s knife.

Comparison Between Traditional and Proposed Health Reimbursement Plan for Primary Care Outcomes Model Across Five Key Domains

Payment Designed for People: Introducing the Primary Care Outcomes Model

A care and payment model that engages primary care physicians in an aligned model built on trust and value could result in better patient care at lower costs.

Figure 1. Differential Changes in Total Medicare Spending for Patients in Accountable Care Organizations (ACOs), According to the Type of ACO, Year of Entry, and Number of Years of Participation.

Medicare Spending after 3 Years of the Medicare Shared Savings Program

After 3 years of the MSSP, participation in shared-savings contracts by physician groups was associated with savings for Medicare that grew over the study period, whereas hospital-integrated ACOs did not produce savings (on average) during the same period.

Reason and Potential Cost Changes for Patients with Treament Recommendation Changes During MD Anderson Cancer Center Multidisciplinary Team Meetings

Great Minds Don’t Always Think Alike

How multidisciplinary team meetings improve cancer care.

Mechanic02_pullquote self-insured employers

Self-Insured Employers — The Payment-Reform Wild Card

Without more private-sector leadership, U.S. health care will remain stuck in a fee-for-service system for the foreseeable future.

Washington State Health Care Authority Center of Excellence joint replacement elements and outcomes of program produces strong patient experience scores

Improving Care by Redesigning Payment

A state-run center of excellence uses benefit design to improve outcomes while controlling cost.

Connect

A weekly email newsletter featuring the latest actionable ideas and practical innovations from NEJM Catalyst.

Learn More »

Topics

Value Based Care

190 Articles

The Evolution of Primary Care: Embracing…

Primary care must leverage disruptive innovations to ensure that patients receive first-access, comprehensive, coordinated, continuous…

Dialysis-Facility Joint-Venture Ownership — Hidden Conflicts…

Despite potential benefits, joint ventures between nephrologists and dialysis companies raise legal and ethical concerns…

Dialysis-Facility Joint-Venture Ownership — Hidden Conflicts…

Despite potential benefits, joint ventures between nephrologists and dialysis companies raise legal and ethical concerns…

Insights Council

Have a voice. Join other health care leaders effecting change, shaping tomorrow.

Apply Now