The Case for Administrative Benchmarks (and Some Challenges)
Published September 20, 2023
NEJM Catal Innov Care Deliv 2023;4(10)
DOI: 10.1056/CAT.23.0194
Summary
Most U.S. Medicare beneficiaries are in population-based programs where spending targets, known as benchmarks, are used to determine payments. These include both the Medicare Advantage (MA) program, which relies on private health plans to manage care, and Accountable Care Organization (ACO) models, where providers are rewarded if they efficiently deliver care. When well designed, these models can incentivize reductions in spending and improve patient outcomes. A crucial aspect of these models, however, is how the benchmarks are determined. Policy makers have multiple approaches at their disposal, and each comes with unique strengths and weaknesses. The most common benchmark setting approach is empirical in that benchmarks are tied to actual spending or near-term forecasts based on lagged spending in fee-for-service traditional Medicare (TM). Empirical benchmarks reduce the risk that plans and providers face from fluctuations in costs that are beyond their control. That risk is absorbed by Medicare, so program spending will rise or fall with TM spending. Empirical benchmark systems have several significant weaknesses — including a ratchet effect and a collective success problem — that make it difficult for plans and providers to share in savings over the long run. This limits the long-term success of these population-based models. In contrast, administrative benchmarks are set by taking a base rate (such as historical spending) and growing it by an administrative factor that can reflect policy goals, anticipated volume, and intensity growth, or a socially agreed-upon rate, such as gross domestic product growth. The key feature is that, without policy action, the benchmark trajectory is not influenced by realized spending trends. An example of the administrative benchmark approach is the Accountable Care Prospective Trend component of the benchmarks for ACOs in the Medicare Shared Savings Program, which uses an initial benchmark, based on baseline spending, that grows based on spending growth that was forecast when the program was launched rather than realized spending growth. This administrative benchmark allows benchmark growth to diverge from, rather than track with, realized spending growth, which avoids shortcomings of empirical benchmarks and allows for greater incentives to deliver care efficiently, providing predictability over time. The key to success for administrative benchmarks is that the administrative growth rate needs to be set low enough so that Medicare saves money relative to what would happen without ACOs or MA, but high enough to still encourage participation.
Notes
This work was supported by a grant from Arnold Ventures. The analysis and content does not necessarily represent the official views of Arnold Ventures.
Michael E. Chernew is the chair of the Medicare Payment Advisory Committee. However, these opinions reflect his personal views and not those of any organization with which he is affiliated. J. Michael McWilliams is a senior advisor to the Center for Medicare and Medicaid Innovation. However, these opinions reflect his personal views and not those of any organization with which he is affiliated. Shivani A. Shah has nothing to disclose.
Information & Authors
Information
Published In
NEJM Catalyst Innovations in Care Delivery
Copyright
Copyright © 2023 Massachusetts Medical Society.
History
Published online: September 20, 2023
Published in issue: September 20, 2023
Topics
Authors
Metrics & Citations
Metrics
Altmetrics
Citations
Export citation
Select the format you want to export the citation of this publication.