New Marketplace

A New Way to Define Value in Drug Pricing

Article · February 24, 2016

Prices for specialty drugs in the United States are out of control, with spending rising much faster than in many other health care domains. Some state Medicaid programs have been driven to the brink by the cost of new drugs for diseases such as hepatitis C, for which 12 weeks of treatment with Sovaldi can cost nearly $100,000.

Many people are cheering a new potential solution: paying for drugs according to how well they actually work. This commonsense idea comes in a few flavors, which I’ll discuss later, but the underlying principles are the same. A drug that works is worth something; one that doesn’t is not. If a new drug works no better than an older one, the two have equal worth. If a drug costs a lot, that’s OK only if it makes people so healthy that it reduces their spending on other forms of health care.

This all sounds like a move toward paying smarter or, in health care lingo, “paying for value.” But one big problem plagues a lot of these (and other) ideas in health care: They just don’t scale. In a vacuum, a particular idea might work for a specific drug, but only if it focuses on isolated factors and ignores the long-term context of treatment, different types of treatment, and multiple (often subjective) aspects of value.

Before I unpack the flaws of existing drug-pricing proposals, let me share a prototype that my colleagues and I at Memorial Sloan Kettering Cancer Center developed. It’s an interactive drug-pricing tool — the DrugAbacus — that integrates objective information about cancer drugs while empowering users to define what value means to them.

Yes, everyone agrees that a drug’s value is tied to its clinical benefit for the patient. But how do you measure the impact of, say, drug side effects? If they’re bad, is the drug less valuable? What about if the drug costs a lot to develop or if its novel mechanism of action breaks new scientific ground? What if it treats a rare disease? Do those considerations add value? The DrugAbacus lets you decide how much these and other factors are related to a drug’s value. The tool’s intended users are policymakers who wish to explore the idea of finding fair prices for drugs while respecting the complexity and subjectivity of what “value” means.

Specifically, the DrugAbacus allows you to choose a dollar amount for each additional year of life that the drug provides (the total number of available life-years is based on scientific evidence of the drug’s efficacy). Next, you decide how much to discount the price for the drug’s side effects. You can also add premiums to the price for advantages such as treating a rare disease or having a novel mechanism of action. The tool then shows you the result — your self-valued DrugAbacus price — and compares it with the drug’s initial market price.

Right now, the DrugAbacus incorporates data on many attributes of 54 recently approved cancer drugs. It still lacks some potentially important information, such as how patients describe their experience with the treatment, and my colleagues and I will address those limitations. Nevertheless, by combining objective data about a drug with the tool user’s own assessment of value, the DrugAbacus has a distinct advantage over alternative drug-pricing proposals:

The Current System

The present-day method of drug pricing has the benefit of simplicity. Manufacturers charge whatever they want. But the problem is obvious: excessively high prices that defy market forces. For example, in today’s dollars Novartis charged $4,540 for a month of the leukemia drug Gleevec as recently as 2001, but now it costs $8,500 in the United States, even though it is just $4,500 and $3,300 a month in Germany and France, respectively. I didn’t cherry-pick this example. Cancer-drug prices in the U.S. are up more than fourfold in the past two decades, after adjustment for inflation.

Paying for Drugs When They “Work”

One alternative to the current system proposes paying for a drug only when it benefits the patient. The concept has been tried: In an agreement with the UK’s National Health Service, the maker of the blood-cancer drug Velcade has to rebate money for the drug when it does not change a patient’s blood count as intended.

However, such an approach does not work when treatment involves multiple drugs or, more importantly, when the marker of benefit to the patient is more opaque. Indeed, the largest gains in cancer care come from giving chemotherapy and other drugs to patients after the cancer appears to (but actually may not) be gone. Many experts say that more than half of our progress in combating breast cancer comes from this type of treatment, called adjuvant therapy. But we can’t definitively pinpoint its success in an individual patient and then price a drug accordingly.

Paying for Drugs When They Yield “Overall Savings”

Other pricing proposals consider how much money a drug ultimately saves by improving a patient’s overall health. Consider Novartis’s plan to charge more for its heart-failure drug Entresto only if the drug succeeds in reducing often-costly hospital admissions for heart failure. And Procter & Gamble and Sanofi-Aventis have entered a program with Health Alliance whereby the drug makers pay for bone fractures that occur when a patient is on their drug Actonel, which is designed to prevent such events. This idea has four drawbacks:

  1. It can’t be applied consistently across drugs. If we link prices for some drugs to the overall savings they produce, many clearly useful drugs will appear to lack value. For instance, drugs that allow leukemia patients to get well enough to progress to a potentially curative but very costly bone-marrow transplant would have a poor price profile because, in the end, they increase total spending. Should we really consider a drug that starts a patient on a path to a possible cure to be of lower value and thus deserving of a lower price?
  2. It does not take a truly long-term view. After all, most interventions that extend life increase total spending in the end, because a patient who lives longer ends up needing more health care. Even Sovaldi, Gilead’s hepatitis C drug, comes out in every analysis as costing, not saving, the system money.
  3. It mistakenly assumes that the savings themselves are correctly priced. Remember that we pay too much for most types of care in the U.S., not just drugs. Pricing a heart-failure drug according to how well it prevents an overpriced hospitalization for heart failure just doesn’t make sense.
  4. It, like other drug-pricing proposals, is at odds with our true goal for health care spending — to innovate our way to a lower-cost system. Overall savings from a drug should be passed through to society at large, not passed back only to the drug maker.

A Modest Next Step

Current drug-pricing proposals simply don’t take the big picture into account. If we try to build a separate pay-for-performance structure for each new drug, we will quickly discover that we can’t come up with a practical one for most drugs. The details for a viable alternative pricing system are not easy to outline, of course. But we can aim for two things:

First, start with a price for a drug given how well it works in initial clinical trials that are intended to win FDA approval. Down the road, recalibrate the price using data on how well the drug helps real patients in practice, potentially captured in medical records, patient registries, and clinical-outcomes research. The new data on the drug’s performance could then be built into a new calculation of value. That kind of approach would reward the most successful innovators. It would also strongly encourage manufacturers to work with providers and insurers to maximize the real-world efficacy of their products so that reimbursement levels are maintained. That means launching more programs to help patients adhere to their prescribed drug regimens — and curbing instances of off-label use that have no health benefit.

Second, work to develop a pricing formula that links price with the ever-elusive “value” of a drug. That’s where the DrugAbacus comes in. The tool makes explicit which features and advantages of a cancer drug get incorporated into its price — and shows how that drug compares with its peers. In short, the tool provides context for value-based decision making about drug pricing.

The DrugAbacus has limitations, as I discussed earlier. But I believe that it provides a template for how we need to start thinking about value in drug pricing — by capturing some of the inherent complexity of value-based decisions without making the fundamentally flawed assumptions that are embedded in other drug-pricing proposals.

New call for submissions ­to NEJM Catalyst

Now inviting longform articles

Connect

A weekly email newsletter featuring the latest actionable ideas and practical innovations from NEJM Catalyst.

Learn More »

More From New Marketplace
Strongwater08_pullquote primary care value proposition and disruptive innovation

The Evolution of Primary Care: Embracing Innovation While Protecting the Core Value

Primary care must leverage disruptive innovations to ensure that patients receive first-access, comprehensive, coordinated, continuous care that is woven into a seamlessly integrated system.

Berns01_pullquote nephrologists dialysis facility joint venture conflicts of interest

Dialysis-Facility Joint-Venture Ownership — Hidden Conflicts of Interest

Despite potential benefits, joint ventures between nephrologists and dialysis companies raise legal and ethical concerns because of participants’ conflicts of interest and lack of transparency.

Fee-for-Service Continues to Account for the Majority of Revenue

New Marketplace Survey: Transitioning Payment Models: Fee-for-Service to Value-Based Care

In a survey of the NEJM Catalyst Insights Council sponsored by Optum, respondents express enthusiasm for value-based care but have conflicting opinions about just how far along that path they should go.

Sample Report Comparing Individual Patient-Reported Outcome Measures with FORCE-TJR National Norms

The Essential Role of Patient-Centered Registries in an Era of Electronic Health Records

Smartly designed patient-centered registries capture longitudinal data to augment EHRs and enhance quality improvement, policy, and research efforts.

Murray02_pullquote surgical care bundled payments accountable care organizations

Surgical Value — Beyond Bundled Payments

The surgeon has a crucial role in defining value for patients in a population — and not just when that patient is in need of the surgeon’s knife.

Comparison Between Traditional and Proposed Health Reimbursement Plan for Primary Care Outcomes Model Across Five Key Domains

Payment Designed for People: Introducing the Primary Care Outcomes Model

A care and payment model that engages primary care physicians in an aligned model built on trust and value could result in better patient care at lower costs.

Figure 1. Differential Changes in Total Medicare Spending for Patients in Accountable Care Organizations (ACOs), According to the Type of ACO, Year of Entry, and Number of Years of Participation.

Medicare Spending after 3 Years of the Medicare Shared Savings Program

After 3 years of the MSSP, participation in shared-savings contracts by physician groups was associated with savings for Medicare that grew over the study period, whereas hospital-integrated ACOs did not produce savings (on average) during the same period.

Reason and Potential Cost Changes for Patients with Treament Recommendation Changes During MD Anderson Cancer Center Multidisciplinary Team Meetings

Great Minds Don’t Always Think Alike

How multidisciplinary team meetings improve cancer care.

Mechanic02_pullquote self-insured employers

Self-Insured Employers — The Payment-Reform Wild Card

Without more private-sector leadership, U.S. health care will remain stuck in a fee-for-service system for the foreseeable future.

Washington State Health Care Authority Center of Excellence joint replacement elements and outcomes of program produces strong patient experience scores

Improving Care by Redesigning Payment

A state-run center of excellence uses benefit design to improve outcomes while controlling cost.

Connect

A weekly email newsletter featuring the latest actionable ideas and practical innovations from NEJM Catalyst.

Learn More »

Topics

Value Based Care

190 Articles

The Evolution of Primary Care: Embracing…

Primary care must leverage disruptive innovations to ensure that patients receive first-access, comprehensive, coordinated, continuous…

Dialysis-Facility Joint-Venture Ownership — Hidden Conflicts…

Despite potential benefits, joint ventures between nephrologists and dialysis companies raise legal and ethical concerns…

Dialysis-Facility Joint-Venture Ownership — Hidden Conflicts…

Despite potential benefits, joint ventures between nephrologists and dialysis companies raise legal and ethical concerns…

Insights Council

Have a voice. Join other health care leaders effecting change, shaping tomorrow.

Apply Now